Type | Working Paper - University of Western Ontario, Economic Policy Research Institute Working Papers |
Title | Earnings and labor mobility in rural China: Implications for China’s WTO entry |
Author(s) | |
Volume | 20028 |
Publication (Day/Month/Year) | 2002 |
URL | http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.196.6235&rep=rep1&type=pdf |
Abstract | The literature on trade liberalization in developing countries contains divergent views regarding the impact of liberalization on employment, incomes, and poverty. While most studies find aggregate welfare gains, they disagree over the distribution of these gains among households. One view is that trade liberalization generates broad-based employment gains across regions for skilled and unskilled labor, and that consequently income gains are shared widely (Dollar and Kraay, 2001). Under these conditions trade liberalization contributes to reductions in inequality and poverty. The alternative view is that employment and income gains go disproportionately to the already better-off groups, with negative implications for inequality and perhaps also for the poor (Rodrik, 2000). Reality likely lies somewhere in between, with the outcome depending on specific conditions in the country in question. First, the impact of liberalization depends on the level and structure of pre-liberalization trade barriers, which determine the sectors that gain and lose. A differential impact on sectors holds implications for the distribution of gains among regions, skill levels, and income groups. Second, it depends on the pre-existing distribution of assets, that is, of land, capital, and human capital. So, for example, if trade liberalization benefits agriculture, and if land holdings are highly concentrated, then inequality could increase. Third, the distributional impact of trade liberalization depends on the flexibility of domestic markets, especially (but not only) for labor. Gains from trade liberalization are less likely to be shared equally where labor markets are segmented and barriers hinder labor mobility across sectors. Thus for specific household groups such as the poor, the impact of trade liberalization depends critically on local market conditions and household endowments (Winters, 2000). These considerations are relevant to the impact of WTO entry and concomitant trade liberalization on employment and incomes in China. In these regards the Chinese case has some interesting features. China’s labor markets have historically (under socialism) been inflexible and highly segmented. Domestic economic reforms have allowed greater labor mobility, but many observers believe that substantial institutional barriers to labor movement 2 persist. Also, in China certain assets such as land and education, while not equally distributed, are nevertheless relatively equally distributed by developing country standards. These two features would have counterbalancing effects in that the former would tend to cause the gains from WTO entry to be concentrated while the latter would tend to cause the gains to be shared more broadly compared to similar liberalizations in other countries. This paper examines the microeconomic determinants of rural employment and incomes in China. Using survey data, we estimate income, wage, and labor supply functions for rural households in China. Since the households derive income from agriculture and sideline family businesses and since labor hired in such activities is fairly rare (see Bowlus and Sicular, forthcoming), we must impute shadow wages derived from self-employment. Together, the income, wage, shadow wage, and labor supply functions empirically describe household income generation from employment. Our analysis fills a gap in the literature. While the literature examining employment and earnings in rural China is now quite substantial, most studies of China’s rural employment analyze the determinants of occupational status, that is, whether or not individuals participate in different types of work such as wage jobs or non-agricultural sidelines (examples are Hare, 1994, 1999a, 1999b, Knight and Song, 1997, 1999; Michelson and Parish, 2000, Parish, Zhe and Li, 1995, Rozelle et al.,1999, and Zhao, 1999a, 1999b). Relatively few studies estimate rural labor supply per se, that is, hours or days worked (examples are Knight and Song, 1997, and Yao, 1999). Even fewer studies estimate labor supply as a function of wages, the relationship of greatest interest here. To our knowledge the only study that estimates labor supply for rural China and includes a measure of the wage as an explanatory variable is by Meng (2000). Like Meng, we estimate time worked as a function of wages and other variables. Unlike Meng, and indeed unlike the relevant literature for other developing countries (Jacoby, 1993, Skoufias, 1994, etc.), our labor supply functions allow for the possibility that wages or shadow wages, and labor’s response to these wages, can differ depending on the type of wage. That is, in our 3 analysis household labor supply is a function of not just one but of multiple wages. Thus it is possible for labor supply to be more responsive to the market wage than to the agricultural shadow wage, or vice versa. Finally, while other studies estimate total labor supply, we estimate total labor supply and also its components, in this case labor supply to household agricultural production, to household non-agricultural production, and to wage employment. By estimating the components of labor supply, we obtain information about how wages and other variables influence the composition of employment. |
» | China - Rural Household Survey 1997 |