Type | Report |
Title | How to achieve pro-poor growth in a poor economy. The case of Burkina Faso |
Author(s) | |
Publication (Day/Month/Year) | 2004 |
URL | http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTPGI/Resources/342674-1115051237044/oppgburkinafaso.pdf |
Abstract | Burkina Faso is a Sub-Saharan, landlocked country, with very limited rainfall, very weak natural resource endowments and with a low human as well as physical capital stock. As a mainly agricultural and cotton exporting country its economic performance depends heavily on climatic conditions and the world market price for cotton. Public revenue is for a large part financed through external aid. Despite the significant economic growth achieved during the last ten years - partly attributable to the currency devaluation in 1994, a favorable development of the world market price for cotton and structural adjustment- and a steady increase in social expenditure, official poverty estimates suggested that poverty did not decrease during that period, but stagnated at a high level with roughly 45% of the population being poor. Hence, the question aroused: Why did the poor not benefit from growth and what should be done so that growth becomes pro-poor in the future? To answer this question first we carried out a reassessment of poverty and inequality trends. Past estimates were mainly affected by three sources of bias: changes in the household survey design, changes in the methodology used to compute household expenditure aggregates, and high relative price variations over time, which were only imperfectly taken into account for the computation of the official national poverty line. In our estimations we corrected these biases as most as possible and estimate that poverty as measured by the headcount index increased strongly between 1994 and 1998 from 55.5% to 61.8% but then decreased substantively between 1998 and 2003 to 47.2%. In rural areas we find roughly the same dynamic only on a higher level. Although through out all three survey years poverty in urban areas remained always significantly lower than in rural areas, we state that urban poverty rose from 14.7% in 1994 to 27.3% in 1998 and then decreased to 20.3% in 2003. Therefore, in contrast to rural areas and despite the fact that it decreased significantly between 1998 and 2003, urban poverty in 2003 was still substantially higher than in 1994. Between 1994 and 1998, inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient increased from 0.45 to 0.50 in urban areas, but decreased significantly in rural areas from 0.39 to 0.35 and on a national level from 0.47 to 0.45. Thereafter between 1998 and 2003, inequality stagnated more or less in urban areas, increased again to 0.39 in rural areas but remained constant on a national level. To conclude, growth between 1994 and 2003, as measured by the growth-elasticity of poverty as well as by the pro-poor growth index, was moderately pro-poor on the national level and in rural areas but not so in urban areas. The growth and inequality decomposition of poverty further revealed that even the only slight decrease of national inequality over the whole observation period contributed substantially to poverty reduction. |