Type | Working Paper |
Title | Heterogeneity, Measurement Error, and Misallocation: Evidence from African Agriculture |
Author(s) | |
Publication (Day/Month/Year) | 2017 |
URL | http://egcenter.economics.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/Conference 2017 Agri-Devospeakers/Gollin_Udry_Heterogeneity, Measurement Error, and Misallocation.pdf |
Abstract | How important is misallocation in explaining the income differences across countries? A recent literature in development and growth economics has focused on misallocation across sectors, firms, and plants. 1 This literature has found evidence that the dispersion of productivity across production units seems to be consistently higher in poor countries than in rich ones. Such productivity differences have the potential to account for a large fraction of the cross-country income differences. In an aggregate sense, misallocation across sectors or firms reduces aggregate total factor productivity (TFP). A challenge in this literature is to distinguish misallocation from other sources of dispersion in productivity, such as technology shocks, measurement error, and adjustment costs of various kinds. This paper seeks to disentangle these different sources of dispersion in an environment where cross-firm differences in productivity are very large, aggregate productivity is low, and market failures undoubtedly contribute to cross-firm frictions in the allocation of resources. Specifically, we take advantage of extraordinarily rich data from farms in three countries in Africa, for which we have detailed panel observations on the same firms producing identical outputs on different plots in the same time period. Since farmers face no market imperfections in allocating resources across their own plots within a growing season, we can use these plot-level data to identify misallocation more precisely. Our strategy allows us to disentangle the productivity dispersion that arises from misallocation from that stemming from measurement error or heterogeneity in technology and inputs (including production shocks). The agricultural sector provides a valuable window through which to study firmlevel misallocation. Most firm surveys have relatively few observations on different plants or establishments operated by the same firm, and this makes it difficult to disentangle firm management from any unobservable characteristics of the plant or factory. Another advantage we have relative to firm surveys is that our producers are producing highly homogeneous products, with little market power. Consequently, we can compare the output of different firms (farms) without worrying about markups and pricing strategies. Understanding the extent of misallocation in agriculture is also of interest because of evidence that low agricultural productivity can explain – at least in a mechanical sense – a large fraction of the cross-country dispersion of output per worker (Caselli 2005, Restuccia et al. 2008). A cluster of recent papers has suggested that there may be very large dispersion in productivity at the level of farms and farmers, potentially indicative of misallocation at this micro level. 2 These papers point out that in poor economies, very large fractions of the workforce are employed in agriculture, in contrast to rich countries, where very few people earn a living from farming. In economies where two-thirds of the people are farmers, it is reasonable to ask whether they are all good at farming – and whether market failures of various kinds may induce too many low-skill farmers to remain in agriculture. Restuccia and Santaeulalia-Llopis (2017), in particular, have raised the intriguing possibility that much of Africa’s productivity deficit might be attributable to misallocation within the agricultural sector. In particular, they find suggestive evidence, based on data from Malawi, that too much farmland is managed by lowskill farmers. If true, this finding might offer an explanation for sub-Saharan Africa’s low productivity in agriculture. Indeed, it might by extension help explain the region’s low levels of income per capita. The finding also suggests a relatively straightforward solution – albeit one with great political complexity – namely, the liberalization of land and input markets, so that the best farmers can eventually buy out those farmers who lack the skill to farm productively. The misallocation hypothesis for African agriculture is particularly plausible because of abundant evidence that the continent’s agricultural markets work poorly – for land, rural labor, intermediate goods, and output. Much land lacks formal title, and rural labor markets are often poorly integrated. Empirical tests consistently reject the hypothesis that markets are complete.3 |
» | Uganda - National Panel Survey 2005-2009 |
» | Uganda - National Panel Survey 2010-2011 |
» | Uganda - National Panel Survey 2011-2012 |
» | Uganda - National Panel Survey 2013-2014 |